Published daily by the Lowy Institute

Financial regulation: Is Australia's 'twin peaks' model a successful export?

Financial regulation: Is Australia's 'twin peaks' model a successful export?
Published 1 Mar 2016 

It is little known outside financial circles, but Australia is enjoying some success on the global stage as a policy exemplar.

Australia's model for the regulation of the financial system – the Twin Peaks model – is being emulated world-wide. So-called because the model is characterised by two equal and independent peaks: the Australian Securities and Investments Commission (ASIC) and the Australian Prudential Regulation Authority (APRA). Because Australia fared relatively well during the GFC and because our regulatory model has been credited with much of our success, a number of other countries have adopted the model (the UK, New Zealand, South Africa) or have signaled a desire to adopt it (South Korea, Hong Kong, and the  federal level of the EU).

Under the Twin Peaks model, one peak is responsible for financial system stability (in our case, APRA) while the other (ASIC) is responsible for good market conduct and consumer protection. Within this system the Reserve Bank remains partly responsible for financial system stability, and remains the lender of last resort. So in fact, the model is a misnomer. It is in fact more correctly called the Triple Peak model.

Crucial to the success of the model is the notion that both regulators are equal in power and importance, and that neither should play second-fiddle to the other. By so doing, the model recognises that if one of the two peak bodies assumed the position of a lead regulator, invariably it would be the financial system stability regulator assuming the role of top dog. Thereafter, policing good market conduct and protecting consumers would begin to decline in importance.

When you consider how the GFC originated – consumer abuse (reckless and predatory lending in the sub-prime industry) combined with market misconduct (fraud on an industrial scale, like that at Countrywide, and the design and sale of financial products designed to fail) — you begin to appreciate the importance of a strong and forceful market conduct and consumer protection peak bodies. [fold]

As a result, in our advice to the South African Treasury in 2014-15, on the first draft of their legislation adopting the Australian model, my colleague Andrew Godwin in the Melbourne Law School and I advised the South Africans to jettison their provisions establishing on of their two peaks as the lead regulator.

The model has much to commend it. It provides a clear remit and certainty of jurisdiction. It ameliorates tendencies towards turf wars, confusion among regulatees as to which regulator may have authority in a given situation or in respect of a particular product, confusion among consumers in countries with multiple regulators as to which one to turn to for assistance, conflicting and contradictory regulatory signals like those produced in countries with multiple regulators, and opportunities to engage in regulatory arbitrage by regulatees. It enables the two regulators to build capacity and specialisation in their field, pool the resources and human capital that would otherwise be spread over multiple regulators, and present a unified front to government.

For good reason, then, Twin Peaks is the model favoured by the Basel Committee, the IMF, G20, World Bank and others. But is it transferable?

Part of what contributed to the model's success in Australia may not be available elsewhere. For example, the model relies upon inter-agency co-operation and collaboration, and in Australia the three peaks have a demonstrated history of close co-operation. The relationship is not riven with rivalry and turf wars, and for the most part they are unfettered by political interference. Australian public servants are highly skilled and largely incorrupt. This is underscored by a professional legal fraternity whose trials are adjudicated over by a fiercely independent judiciary, uncorrupted, and existing within a state based upon the rule of law.

By comparison, South Africa, the most recent adopter, either lacks  some of those same attributes, or if it has them, they are not as strongly evident. Add to this the fact that at the advent of the GFC Australian banks were preoccupied with their home market and therefore less exposed internationally. The banks had a 'vanilla' investment profile, which is to say they were less exposed to esoteric, highly leveraged and highly derived financial products. This is partly why Australia fared well during the GFC. Future adopters, with more internationally inter-connected banking systems, may fare worse under the same crisis conditions.

That was certainly the case with the Netherlands, the second country to adopt Twin Peaks, in 2002. The GFC proved catastrophic for the Dutch banking sector, with total foreign claims on Dutch banks amounting to 300% of GDP. Yet if you look across the characteristics that explain Twin Peaks' success in Australia, you see the same characteristics strongly evident in the Dutch state. All except for a vanilla banking sector.

Added to this international failure of the model are some domestic setbacks, most notably HIH and the near failure of Zurich, as well as the performance of ASIC in the financial advice scandals (a performance excoriated by the Senate). Consequently, while Twin Peaks does have much to commend it, it is by no means a panacea to financial crises and contagion. It is merely one arrow in an increasingly technical and disparate quiver.

Image courtesy of Wikipedia.




You may also be interested in